Encyclopedia
| Library | Reference
| Teaching | General
| Links | About
ORB | HOME
The Men Behind the Masque:
Office-holding in East Anglian boroughs, 1272-1460
[contents]
Conclusion
At the close of this study, if one thing is
evident it is that there is no simple, or single, label that will
serve to categorise the government of boroughs in the later Middle
Ages. We can certainly find examples of
oligarchies in the boroughs:
the period of power of Stace and le Rente in Ipswich is a clear case,
assuming the charges laid against them to be accurate (as they seem);
and there is at least a suggestion of oligarchic ambition in the
behaviour of the rulers of Norwich and Lynn in the late fourteenth
and early fifteenth centuries. Yet it would be dangerous to assume
that these, the more conspicuous affairs in the boroughs' political
history, were other than interludes in a normally more restrained,
more harmonious relationship between rulers and ruled. It is precisely
in the context of extreme political developments that we find the most
forceful expressions of popular objection.[1]
Study of the governing personnel - for government itself is an abstract
when separated from the men who interpreted and directed it - reveals
a diversity which makes categorisation difficult: such is the stuff
of history. At this point in historiographical time, the historian
must be concerned, not with attempting to characterise borough
government generally, but with the nature of the governments in
individual boroughs. Some general suggestions and conclusions may
be offered here, but it must be borne in mind that they depend largely
on the evidence from only a handful of examples not necessarily 'typical'.
Evidence has been presented to show that
the political hierarchy may be overlaid with hierarchies of wealth
and age. Yet an attempt to classify the borough rulers as a
plutocracy or a patriarchate would swiftly founder on presentation
of contradictory examples which cannot be dismissed as exceptions
to the rule. Occasionally, relatively young men attained high position
in the political hierarchy, and men of apparently only moderate means
mixed with the richest townsmen in the same positions. Nor would
it be difficult to point to burgesses, qualified by wealth and by
the experience of age, whose participation in government was negligible
or non-existent. Even were either or both of the above labels
applicable, this would not necessarily be helpful in understanding
the character of borough politics. If men in executive office or
in the upper levels of the conciliar structure tended to be the
older members of the community, this owes much to the time required
to work one's way through the hierarchy of offices - a hierarchy
that became increasingly elaborate and formal as the ranks of
officialdom grew - combined with the comparatively low average
life-expectancy. In a community where the number of qualified
(i.e. enfranchised) persons was
quite small to begin with, the group in whose hands the real power of
decision lay seems more a class of survivors than a senatorial elite
monopolising government to the unjust exclusion of others.
Similarly, wealth was no formal pre-requisite
for office, but there were good practical reasons why the wealthier
townsmen were the heaviest participants in government. Wages of
service were not commensurate to the outlay in terms of personal
expense and, more importantly, time which would otherwise be spent
in making a living. Illicit profits from service were not as great
in borough as in royal office, and the risks involved in taking
such profits could be borne only by those already wealthy enough to
buy their way back into favour. There is a good measure of truth in
the medieval saying that "Pore be hangid by the neck; a rich man bi
the purs."[2] Ample evidence remains
to indicate the unpopularity of office-holding, although precisely
how general was this attitude it is difficult to say. There was
certainly a small number of townsmen who actively courted office; and
a somewhat larger group may be said at the least to have acquiesced
in their repeated election to high office. These were the backbone
of urban government. It may be that they did desire and pursue
office, but this can remain only a hypothesis when our records are
not so intimate as to reveal the behind-scenes machinations of
politics. And, on the whole, it is not a hypothesis that one is
inclined to accept readily. Office was probably seen by most as
a burden; although the growing consciousness, towards the close
of the Middle Ages, of its enhancement of social prestige and of
the advantages of manipulating justice and
administration[3] alleviated this
to an extent. However, it was recognised that the duties of
administration must be borne, and it was clear enough that the
wealthier townsmen were best able to shoulder the burden. It may
even be, as Dobson suggests, that the accumulation of great wealth
by individuals, in the face of corporations barely able to balance
their budgets, was tolerated by the community only because those
individuals bore the heaviest responsibilities of protecting and
preserving borough liberties and
prosperity.[4] It is reasonably clear,
at least, that no man was required to serve in a position the
liabilities and responsibilities of which were greater than he
could manage, although every burgess
was expected to participate in government to some degree - even if no
more than in tithing or tax
collection roles, or simply in attending
assemblies.[5]
If wealth and age were not, as such,
qualifications or pre-requisites for office, a greater importance
seems to have been attached to experience, skill, and wisdom. This
we may conclude from the political hierarchy, structured to ensure
that men who attained positions of greatest authority and
responsibility had been tutored in administration and versed in the
needs and resources of the borough, through holding a series of
subordinate offices. We could reach the same conclusion from the
specifications that officers be chosen from men of capability,
faculty, and sufficiency. Clerical and legal skill was taken
into consideration, for some posts more than others, but even
merchants or prosperous tradesmen and artisans were believed to
be qualified: worldly-wise, familiar with the workings of the
courts, successful in negotiations with their fellows, able to
speak for the borough to external authorities. It is not insignificant
that town councils evolved, in all probability, from more hazy
groups already associated with advisory functions and with rendering
of judgements in some court context. We may trace professionalism
back this early, in that the customary law by which the towns were
largely administered was retained in the minds of these men, from
whom, subsequently, executive officers were chosen to preside over
newly-independent borough courts. It does not appear that all
towns committed their customs to writing from the beginning; and,
when they did, the lists seem not so much comprehensive as
representative of the more intricate cases. Again, the single,
professional town clerk particularly responsible for advising the
corporation on matters of borough law - a role that sometimes
specialised to the point of mutation into the office of Recorder - is
not generally manifest until the early fourteenth century.
What we must always remember is that medieval
men desired, above all, efficient government that promoted the
well-being of the whole community while adhering to the principles
of justice, consensus, and harmony. The history of medieval Italian
cities shows the extremes to which townsmen might be willing to go
to obtain this. Be it democracy, oligarchy, or dictatorship: the
end was more important than the means; in this at least Machiavelli
was well-attuned to the mainstream of lay political thought. Indeed,
it is to Italy that we must look for the most explicit theorising
about the qualities of government, such as to Brunetto Latini's
Trésor. Lest we think that Italian city-state politics
have no relevance to English urban history, we should note that
extracts from Latini were included, only one generation after his
work was written, in the compilation of the Liber Custumarum
of London (tempore Edward II), a work that may well have
been consulted by other towns seeking constitutional guidance from
the mother of English cities. The extracts included a list of
twelve qualities Latini held to be desirable in a good
ruler,[6] and the London scribe of
the book of customs declared them worthy of being taken into
consideration when mayors of London
were elected. This revealing, if idealistic, list indicates that a man
chosen to rule his peers should:
- Possess a wisdom that derives from experience, which itself is
the product of age.
- Possess a noble heart that leads him to conduct his life
honourably; electors should not be influenced by power stemming
from personal attributes or family background.
- Be committed to the principle of justice - considered a very
important quality.
- Possess rationality: the ability to perceive truth, and to
know what course of action is the best to follow; in other words, to
be a man of intelligence.
- Be objective (as opposed to gullible); a man was to be judged by
his actions, not his appearance.
- Not be covetous either of money or prestige.
- Be a good speaker, capable of diplomacy and wisdom (discretion?)
in speech.
- Not be extravagant in his personal expenditure; presumably such
habits would influence his expenditure of public monies.
- Not be of immoderate temper (i.e. quick to anger).
- Be rich and magnanimous; this to ensure he could not be corrupted
by offer of money, preferring to give than to receive.
- Hold no other office (the concern here seems to be with division
of attentions, rather than conflict of interest).
- Be faithful and loyal to God and to the people; Latini considered
this as the "chief quality".
Even if it was too much to expect that any man
match up to such standards, the combination of experience and of the
element of paternalism in corporation policies might lead us to
characterise borough government as a
meritocracy.[7] Yet somehow this seems
too approbatory a title for a group motivated, arguably, as much
by self-interest as by concern for community welfare. Aristocracy
may be the most acceptable description, so long as we take 'government
by the best' to refer not to moral character but to
capability,[8] and we might cautiously
qualify the title as 'aristocracy of wealth' to avoid presumptions
of hereditability of power, which the facts do not justify.
If this is considered the nearest we can come
to a classification, however imperfect, we must nonetheless return
to the terms democracy and oligarchy, with which this study was begun.
It is difficult to doubt that democratic principles were the foundation
of the borough constitution: popular election (direct or indirect),
consultation or consensus, and the accountability of officers - with
the ultimate right of the community to depose officers guilty of
maladministration. All these express the basic tenet of borough
politics, that the community was the
ultimate source of authority. This is well expressed by John de Viterbo,
who was no political philosopher but rather an administrator of Florence
in 1228; in his treatise on urban government he wrote (concerning
consultation) that "The principle to be followed is that all shall approve
matters which concern all: let the judgement of all decide the future of
all."[9] This was as true for English
as for Italian cities, and as true for the fifteenth as the thirteenth
century, but let us not forget that the translation of principles into
reality tends to be modified by issues of practicability. Professor
Reynolds was right to doubt that urban political history displays any
great trend towards or away from democracy over the course of the later
medieval period.[10] Any search for so
blatant a transition will be liable to blind students to the
real significance of the actual changes, subtle, for the most part
gradual, an interaction of various influences. Elements of democracy
and oligarchy co-existed in urban government throughout, not uneasily,
yet a measure of tension between them necessitated periodic
readjustment of the constitution to find a workable balance.
Modification took the form of circumscribing executive power through
the elaboration of constitutional checks[11]
and emphasis on accountability, while at the same time restrictions
were being placed on direct popular involvement in decision-making.
Yet to interpret this latter trend as the growth of oligarchy would
be to ignore the larger numbers, drawn from a broader social spectrum,
participating in government in the fifteenth century. Perhaps, in
the last resort, the changes reduce to a growth in consciousness
of the classes composing the urban populace: consciousness of
their relationships, their differing interests, and the role of
government in shaping and reconciling the same, as well as of
government itself not merely as a necessary function but as a
corporate entity. Experimentation and more detailed, precise
definition are prominent features of urban constitutional development.
If democratic principles were modified - even
consciously subverted in some cases, it might be possible (although
not easy) to argue - the aim was to bring the theory of borough
government more in line with the equally long-established practice.
The reconciliation of democratic and aristocratic elements in
government was not to the medieval townsman the incongruity it
might seem to the modern mind; indeed, it was felt that government
at its best combined aspects of monarchy, aristocracy, and
democracy.[12] Latini's list of
desirable attributes of rulers suggests a realization that the
quality of government depended more on the character of leaders
than on the soundness of governmental institutions (whereas in the
Church the opposite theory held sway). Aristocratic and democratic
elements both had long traditions, the latter in the
folkmoot,[13]
the former in the informal proto-conciliar groups that we posit as
influential in administration even prior to the epoch of self-government.
The crystallisation of those groups into formal councils may have
been intended to bring the men of influence in the borough under
some degree of popular control. On the other hand, we cannot
dismiss the possibility that, in some cases at least, councils
evolved by expanding the sphere of operations of existing
bodies.[14] Within the borough
council lay the seeds of change. The achievement of life-membership
status, when combined with co-optative electoral methods, removed
what was effectively the decision-making section of the community
from popular control (short of revolution). And it ruined an
original purpose of the council in representing the community-at-large
in government; although it is difficult to believe that early
councils could ever have been genuinely representative, given the
conditions mentioned above favouring office-holding by the urban
upper class. The consequence of this change, distancing the
original council membership from popular
control,[15] was the creation of
second councils to represent the community. The model of the two-tiered
parliament, with its estates of lords and commons, was perhaps not so
far from the minds of the ruling class, and terminology of the fifteenth
century seems to reflect this somewhat. Although two councils served
to institutionalise rather than heal the division between
classes/estates, while the lower council remained under popular
electoral control the effective role of democracy in borough
government remained pretty much at the level it had been before. Since
the executive was selected from the personnel of the upper councils,
the change also increased his independence from popular control,
particularly given the division of electoral authority (in Norwich
and Lynn) between the two enfranchised estates.
Equally important in undermining democratic
principles was the evolution of the executive committee, a feature
even more common to our towns than change in the status of the
upper council. This elite had no formal place in the fifteenth
century constitutions and was therefore not subject to direct
control. Yet there seems no doubt that it was the most influential
group in government: at it, rather than the council generally,
was aimed the Lynn reform movement of the early fifteenth century;
at Colchester it came to control the aldermannic positions in the
council, and at Maldon it had completely displaced the wardemen
as the decision-making body by the mid-sixteenth century; at
Ipswich it formed the majority in the comparatively small council
of portmen. Since experience was valuable in borough government, it
is easy to see how the executive committee, which dominated
assembly meetings in terms of visibility, could have dominated
decision-making. It is not as easy to judge how important a
contribution to this development were the judicial powers accorded
to the elite by the king in his expansion of the royal network of
local administration. What we see therein is another of the
contradictions in the urban constitution: the application of
both ascending and descending theories of authority; the strong
role of the monarchy in England checked not only the degree of
urban independence, compared to continental towns, but also the
application of populist theories to borough government.
When we look beyond purely political
developments for causes of change, the waters grow murkier. Economic
and demographic deterioration from the late fourteenth century have
been used to explain seemingly oligarchic developments. However,
the so-called 'urban decline' is itself a questionable phenomenon,
not necessarily general; East Anglia perhaps weathered the storm
better than most areas,[16] although
even the fortunes of the towns studied here varied widely. Yet if
the gulf between classes was not still widening, certainly an
awareness of the gulf (of its size, rather than its existence) was
awakening in the consciousness of townsmen. In the growth of
ceremony we see not only the formal expression of social superiorities,
but also the whole gamut of social relationships; ceremony, while
it pointed out the differences, also attempted to demonstrate the
binding ties that made the notion of community a
reality.[17] The segments of this
community were interdependent: the rulers were relied on for
benevolent and efficient government, and the ruled for obedience,
since the power of urban administrations was less coercive than
consensual. Had class antagonisms been as intense as some have
claimed, there would surely be more evidence than we find of
violent conflict in the boroughs?
The normally peaceful course of borough
politics suggests that government largely conformed to expectations
of aristocracy rather than oligarchy. It is difficult to justify
charges of monopolisation of office when we look closely at the
evidence. The component families of the urban upper class were
linked by intermarriage and common interests - not least, admittedly,
the desire to preserve the status quo - but there was a good deal
of rivalry and of diversity in backgrounds too. Merchants may have
predominated, but artisans and professionals were not meagrely
represented, and we have also the more nebulous land-owning
interest. Furthermore, individuals tend not to fit so neatly into
any of these individual categories to the point where we might
hypothesise a clearly delineated division, and conflict, of interests.
To try to identify an elite of families monopolising government
would produce a group so large that, when compared to the enfranchised
population, it would hardly appear an elite at all. Besides, such
a task would be quickly frustrated by the mobility within the ranks
of the ruling class. For the many reasons enumerated elsewhere in
this study, the ruling families were not even coming close to
maintaining their representation in government from one generation
to the next, and there was plenty of room for new men, either
immigrating in a generally promotional pattern from smaller
communities, or rising from lower ranks of the borough community.
For a man of capability and ambition, no matter what his background,
there was no serious obstacle to him rising to the pinnacle of borough
society and government. The structured promotionalism of the
administrative hierarchy, with promotion dependent partly on popular
will, is itself a sign of the open character of medieval urban
government.
If the effective exercise of power devolved
upon a relatively small group, this is a feature common to political
systems and not incompatible with democracy. It is too easy to
condemn the past by using as a yardstick the standards of modern
western democracies. Yet, in fact, one might be hard-pressed to find
a fundamental difference between the political systems of the medieval
borough and the parliamentary democracies of western nations of the
twentieth century. Consider the following characteristics:
- no direct control over the government, except at election time;
- restriction of electoral rights to those who have taken up citizenship;
- no direct control over selection of the executive;
- upper council not elected, but appointed by other members of
the government, generally for life, and chosen on the basis of
superior experience and wisdom;
- actual power of day-to-day government concentrated in the hands
of an executive committee, over whose selection the electorate has
minimal control;
- a promotional system, whereby politicians work their way through
the ranks and are evaluated for leadership roles partly on a basis
of their experience in government;
- participation in office-holding by only a minority of those qualified;
- the tendency for political leaders to be persons who have acquired
wealth and/or status in other walks of life;
- the cult of the leader as the focal point of popular expectations
of government;
- popular participation at governmental assemblies prohibited
(except by invitation), and a representation system imposed instead;
- decisions of highest importance rarely referred back to the community;
- an emphasis on financial accountability, through formal auditing
procedures and/or auditing officers;
- periodic public complaints about excessive taxation, government
corruption, or misuse of public funds.
Are these more (or less) applicable to the medieval than to the modern
situation? Plus ça change, plus c'est le même chose.
If we are hardly in a position to criticize
the fact of power devolving to small groups of borough rulers, nor
should we assume that efforts of governmental elites to strengthen
their hold on power were necessarily inspired by corrupt motives. The
pressure imposed by the community for profitable government, and
pressure from the king for peaceful and orderly rule, likely provided
sufficient impetus in themselves. A number of factors, more
naturalistic than sinister, might be suggested to explain why, as
the later Middle Ages progressed, there was a clamping down on
democratic impulses inherent in the concept of the borough as a
community of peers. In part it was a
perhaps inevitable consequence of the general formalising, legalising,
and bureaucratising of government: a tendency to emphasise structure
and procedures. This encouraged a 'closed shop' approach which favoured
orderliness. At the same time, government is, by its nature, a response
to problems facing society. If life went on entirely harmoniously,
we would need government for very little. As borough governments
faced problems and crises, their members doubtless felt the need
to exercise greater control over the course of events - not least
in order to protect themselves from blame if things got out of hand
and came to the king's attention. So they wished to concentrate
power in their own hands, and subdue the unruly power of the
community. A further factor might be that at the beginning of
independent borough government, in the early thirteenth century,
burgesses looked inward - at the commune - for the answers about
how to govern themselves. By the fifteenth century, there was a
growing sense of the larger sphere - the development of parliament
and the war with France perhaps playing significant roles here - of
nationalism; in the national sphere the dominant model for
government was King and Council, with a representative assembly to
petition and assent.
Since the proof of the pudding was in the
eating, constitutional change was not obnoxious even to the
conservative townsman. We need not resort to burgess apathy to
explain changes apparently detrimental to popular rights; apathy
is never easy to gauge, but it seems that the townsmen's interests
were aroused when occasion warranted. Voluntary acquiescence seems
a better explanation, although it is true that an otherwise
unorganised populace may have relied on the appearance of leaders
before underlying discontent could find forceful
expression.[18] How far we may trust
those expressions for an accurate picture of misgovernment is
uncertain, for popular complaints are complicated by personal
ambitions, group rivalries, and perhaps also misunderstandings of
administrative procedures. Furthermore, resolution of the conflicts
too often are not recorded, or were forestalled by the purchase
of pardons (not in themselves a certain admission of guilt), or
produced settlements so moderate in nature as to suggest that
problems were not perceived as being deep-rooted in the constitutional
arrangement. Indeed, rightly or wrongly, complaints were directed
at erring rulers more than at the system itself, for the error was
seen as basic human failing. Perhaps it was, for our investigation
of the illegal activities of the ruling personnel shows, if not a
prevalent, then an unfortunate degree of opportunism, corruption,
and disregard for the law and for the principle of rule by law. Yet,
in a society where self-interest and self-help were almost essential
to success in life, governmental failings were not to be eradicated
by the exchange of one set of ruling personnel for another. The
temptations towards abuse of office were greater than many could
resist; even the best-intentioned were susceptible to the
corrupting influence of power or, by association with others less
reputable, were entrapped in a web of events beyond their control.
One who had cause to know left this poignant epitaph for the medieval
politician:
Who meaneth to remove the rock
Owt of the slimy mud
Shall mire himself, and hardly scape
The swelling of the flood. [19]
|

INTRODUCTION
Structure of Borough Government |
Social and Economic Background of Office-Holders
Monopolisation of Office |
Attitudes Towards Office-holding |
Professionalism in Administration
Quality of Government |
Conflict and Solidarity in Urban Politics
CONCLUSION