Encyclopedia
| Library | Reference
| Teaching | General
| Links | About
ORB | HOME
The Men Behind the Masque:
Office-holding in East Anglian boroughs, 1272-1460
[contents]
Introduction
Although the character of government has been one
of the most frequently addressed subjects in the field of the history of
later medieval English towns, approaches to this sensitive issue have
tended to focus on constitutional development and internal
power-struggles between rival factions and classes. I use the
term 'sensitive' because the absence of consensus amongst historians
derives partly from the fact that interpretations centre on the
value-charged concepts of democracy and
oligarchy. The earliest
studies tend to be the most obviously partisan. Brady, in 1690, set
out to justify the closed corporations of his day by tracing their
ancestry back to the first royal charters of liberties. Merewether
and Stephens fuelled the reform movement of the 1830s by portraying
borough governments as democracies thwarted by the device of
incorporation at the close of
the Middle Ages.
Later interpretations, while conforming to the
general historiographical environment emphasising development and
transition, continued to diverge widely from one another. As a
consequence of his emphasis on the rising influence of the
Merchant Gild (as opposed
to the diminishing role currently attributed to it) Gross concluded
that an originally democratic community came to be dominated by a
select group of merchants who monopolised power, a process he
described as "the great municipal revolution", albeit a silent and
gradual one. Colby simultaneously arrived at much the same conclusion.
But within a few years Alice Green, refusing to believe that history
could be anything but an upwards progress, reinterpreted the evidence;
she described the modification of an originally oligarchic form of
government as the result of often forceful assertions by a populace
inspired by democratic sentiments (which underlay the realities of
practical administration). Even such a scholar as Tait found that
the evidence could be made to fit both interpretations. Initially
favouring that of Gross and Colby, his study of the rise of the Common
Council led him more towards the Green thesis, although he remained
skeptical of how truly democratic that institution
was.[1]
These disagreements are only partially explicable
by pointing to the diverse routes of constitutional development taken by
different towns, for even students working on the same individual town have
put forward opposing interpretations. Thus, prompted perhaps by Strutt's
insistence on the inalienability of community authority, W.G. Benham
(to whom the historian is indebted for the publication of a substantial
part of Colchester's medieval records) held that "From an unknown
period ... Colchester enjoyed local liberty and self-government on
singularly democratic lines."[2]
Geoffrey Martin, on the other hand, has denied that the popular
assembly in Colchester ever had a significant share in power, whilst
by the end of the Middle Ages "the governing body wears the look of
a self-perpetuating oligarchy with only the sketchiest elements of
popular election."[3] Again, Gray
and Potter declared that Ipswich and Norwich had unusually democratic
constitutions and never became closed corporations, although more
careful studies by Weinbaum and Martin emphasised the strictly limited
role of the Ipswich community compared to the initiative in the hands
of the office-holding body, and Hudson portrayed a transition from
democracy to oligarchy in Norwich.[4]
Current orthodoxy, reflected notably in the
Oxford History of England and in Colin Platt's work summarising
our knowledge of English medieval towns, is that democratic elements held,
from the first, little real power in urban government. That government
was, rather, controlled by an elite - or a succession of elites, since the
sporadic popular upheavals served only to replace one set of rulers
with another - characterised by social and economic prominence in the
community, for wealth and authority were natural concomitants. These
rulers - that is, office-holders - increasingly monopolised ('usurped'
would be a more prejudicial term) participatory access to
decision-making and eventually evolved into the notorious closed
corporation. The opposing view, along the lines laid out by Green,
now finds few proponents, although Bridbury has argued that, socially
and politically, greater flexibility and accessibility were features
of the fifteenth century town, and a recent study of Oxford's town
council in that period has stressed the same open
character.[5]
Modification of the oligarchic interpretation
has also been advocated by Susan Reynolds; while Platt's book may be
seen as the summation of an era of research into medieval borough
history, Reynolds' cautious and balanced study, appearing in print
immediately afterwards, points to the problems on which historians
must now focus. She points out that:
The trouble with talking in terms of oligarchy and democracy is that
oligarchy is a pejorative word: it traditionally implies not merely
government by the few, but selfish government by the few. Modern
writers tend to assume that all governments of the few must be
selfish.[6]
'Democracy' too conjures up in the modern mind
much more than it is likely to have done in the mind of the modern
townsman. Green's belief that "if the towns had been called on for
a confession of faith, the declaration of a pure and unadulterated
freedom would have been in every mouth"[7]
is perhaps more reflective of the sentiments of her own time than those
of the medieval townsman, although it has some validity for the latter.
Practical government, not political philosophy, was their prime concern.
If we seek to discover that philosophy from the records they left, it is
rarely forthcoming except from inference and deduction.
There are, then, two areas upon which this
study proposes to focus. First, whether the terms democracy
and oligarchy, although imperfect, are the most satisfactory
that we possess to apply to borough government. Effective rule by an
elite (not in itself incompatible with democracy) is not so much at issue.
But was the behaviour of this elite self-interested, as that of an
oligarchy must be? Was it paternalistic, an aristocracy, fitting
the expectations of the medieval townsmen themselves? Does the apparent
association of wealth with power allow us to use the term
plutocracy? Or does the less commonly noticed predominance
of the longest-living, most experienced of the leading townsmen in
the upper ranks of government suggest that we are dealing with a
patriarchate - or, to use Hammer's term,
gerontocracy?[8] Secondly,
whether constitutional theory harmonised with the realities of
day-to-day government, whether they developed along the same lines,
at the same rate, or whether a divergence between the two may help
to explain the contradictory interpretations that have plagued the
historiography of this field.
It is intended to approach these questions
through an examination of the governmental systems of several East
Anglian towns: in Norfolk, (King's)
Lynn, Norwich, and
Great Yarmouth; in Suffolk,
Ipswich; and in Essex,
Colchester and Maldon.
This examination will rely chiefly on prosopographical analysis of the
group of men who held the more important borough offices between the
reigns of Edward I (in which period the regular keeping of borough
records becomes widely established[9])
and Henry VI. Biographical data on almost 1300 office-holders has
been compiled. It is not suggested that prosopography is the only
nor necessarily the best approach. Yet, if justification were
elicited, it might be noted that government is essentially the
making of decisions and enforcing of the same via the exercise of
power, and that both processes are strongly influenced by the human
factor. As Meyer noted: "the folk of the later Middle Ages, like
those of today, were governed by men and not laws, despite legal
or political pronouncements."[10] If
borough government never managed to measure up to the high standards
expected of it - as complaints of the time suggest - or if it
mutated from its originally intended form to another, the fault
may lie with human behaviour as much as weaknesses inherent in
the administrative machinery. With that in mind, this study will
use simple prosopographical statistics[11]
and individual biographical examples to throw light on six
particular topics:
- the relationship of office to wealth and social position;
- the degree of monopolisation of power by an artificially small
percentage of the population;
- attitudes suggesting the desirability or undesirability of
office-holding;
- the extent of professionalism in administration;
- the quality of government; and
- the nature of urban power-struggles.
Prosopography has its own particular problems,
as well as sharing others common to all types of research. Perhaps
the most grievous is the lack of information. Richards, having entered
biographical accounts of eminent local men of religion into his history
of Lynn, desired to do the same for laymen, but lamented: "alas! we
look and search for them in vain: hardly can one be found whose
name deserves to be recorded, or remembered by posterity." Even
the better-informed May McKisack, in her study of parliamentary
burgesses, complained that of a large number: "There is little to
be said of them as individuals, for most of them have left no memorial
save a few sparse references."[12]
Others have been more optimistic, preferring to emphasise the
information we still have, rather than that now lost or never
recorded.[13]
As regards the compilation of lists of
officials, this has been achieved, for those towns addressed by
this study, with few gaps during the fourteenth and fifteenth
centuries; only for the reign of Edward I are data unsatisfactory.
Although few townsmen figure so prominently in the records as to
permit the reconstruction of whole lives and careers with some
confidence, enough may be learned to render a good majority susceptible
to statistical analysis relating to most questions posed by this
study.[14] Of 843 office-holders
identified from the three principal towns researched, only 3% yield
no more information than their tenure of
office.[15] However, because records
tend to focus on the affairs of the wealthier townsmen, it is rarely
possible to examine more than one side of the coin: that section of
the urban community generally described as the oligarchy.
One or two specialised problems must be noted.
By the fourteenth century the hereditary surname was fairly common
in towns and long enough established to be no longer a reliable
indicator of occupation, parentage, or place of
birth;[16] indeed, there is ample
evidence to show that they were highly misleading in this respect.
Some surnames continued to fluctuate during the later Middle Ages,
obscuring pedigrees, whilst not a few men went by more than one
surname: for example, John Ashenden of Lynn was occasionally called
not only by his occupational surname of Brouster, but also by the
name of Taylour (although there is no evidence for his participation
in the craft); and William de Causton of Ipswich was also known as
le Clerk and as Hering. The greater the amount of biographical
data collected, the greater the chance of making these identifications,
not always explicit in the documents. This, it is hoped, is the case
with the individuals falling under this study; but it cannot be
ruled out that information has been missed because of a failure to
make an identification, or that two office-holders included in
analysis might in fact be a single person under different surnames.
More difficult to distinguish from each other
are different men of the same name, a problem intensified by the
very common occurrence of a limited number of Christian names in
this period, and the tendency to name children after other members
of the family. An extreme case: in 1331 Thomas de Debenham, in
claiming before Ipswich court a hereditary right to three shops,
revealed that he was the sole survivor of seven brothers, five of whom
had been named John![17] For further
instance, the name Henry Bosse may be found in frequent occupation of
Colchester offices between 1357 and 1433; this resolves into three
individuals, but where the career of each ends and begins is a matter for
speculation, for none has left a will. The same may be said of the two
Geoffrey Starlings of Ipswich, whose careers overlap in the 1370s. It
may be appreciated, therefore, that when the researcher is faced by
a John Clerk or a John Smith, he is inclined to despair at ever
disentangling the numerous individuals of those names, or determining
if there is any family relationship with others of the same surname.
The John Clerk who was bailiff of Colchester in 1373 was probably
the merchant of that name, but he may have been one of the others
who entered the franchise as "king's retainer" (1350/1) or weaver
(1354). There is a list of candidates for the John Smith who sat
in parliament for Ipswich in the 1440s: John Smith chandler, John
Smith fuller, John Smith barker, John Smith atte Cay merchant, John
Smith atte Cross, John Smith junior mercer, John Smith of Stoke,
John Smith "recently of Akenham", and others all living in Ipswich
during the reign of Henry VI. Given these uncertainties, one cannot
expect precision from statistical analysis.
This study has even more serious limitations.
No definitive conclusions on the underlying theme of the character
of borough government can be drawn from a few case-studies; but to
investigate every town, or at least every major town, in the depth
required would involve a vast amount of time. As far as this work
is concerned, the records pertaining to Lynn, Ipswich, and Colchester
have been carefully searched and their fruits have been the foundation
of the study. Varying degrees of work have been done on Great
Yarmouth, Norwich and Maldon: the Yarmouth records have been sampled,
but much information has been gathered from secondary sources; the
Maldon records, although not plentiful, have all been read through,
but secondary material on the town is scarce; time has permitted
Norwich records to be consulted only in their printed version and
office-holders have not been studied individually. The history
of each one of these towns has benefited from the attentions of
scholars, both antiquarian and modern. Prosopographical data relating
to prominent townsmen has been compiled and used effectively by
several of the more recent studies.[18]
Where this study hopes to profit is not merely from concentrating on
particular aspects of urban administration (as opposed to attempting
the overview found in pioneering researches), but also from comparison.
The towns under investigation, all in the prosperous and populous
eastern part of the country, all with strong links to maritime
trade, existed in a broadly common economic environment. Some
problems in administrative and political development were also
common, others the product of peculiar circumstances, and the
solutions were likewise. By contrasting these towns we may perhaps
learn something that is not easily perceived from isolated studies.
A further limitation has been the grades
of officials studied. The permanent officials of the
bureaucracy - clerks, sergeants and minor officers - whose annual
election disguises reappointment, and who had no voice in
decision-making, have not come under scrutiny. The personnel
of the town councils have not been directly analysed either, due
to the infrequent recording of memberships in most of those towns
studied. However, in effect, a large proportion of the councillors
will be found to fall under the categories that have been analysed.
These include the most commonly studied groups: the executive
(mayors and
bailiffs) and parliamentary burgesses.
The latter are not town rulers per se, but the importance of their
role to the town they represented makes worthwhile an examination of
their relationship (supposing there to be such) to the urban
ruling class; henceforth they will be referred to, for brevity's
sake, as M.P.s, although this term is not to be thought of with
its modern connotations but purely meaning a representative of
a constituency at a single meeting of parliament. In addition,
partly to enlarge the size of the group, partly in an attempt to
deal with a broader social range than has been investigated by others,
this study encompasses other important elected officers: financial
officers (from those five towns whose personnel have been analysed)
and also the coroners of Ipswich.[19]
The Colchester records suggest a justification for this selection
of offices. There, two elections were held annually: bailiffs,
town council and chamberlains
were elected in early September; other officers were not so vital to
the government and their election was left until just after the new
administrative year began at Michaelmas.[20]
This study was originally undertaken to fulfill
the requirements for the degree of Master of Philosophy at the
University of Leicester, 1978-1982. The present text represents
an expansion of my thesis, based principally upon work conducted at
that time but excluded (largely for reasons of space) from the thesis,
yet also with some additions deriving from subsequent research. I
benefited greatly, in the course of my original research, from
discussions with my Leicester colleague David Wykes and former
colleague (from my time at Carleton University, when I was studying
the government of medieval Norwich) Rudi Aksim - both involved in
prosopographical studies of their own; also with the late
Helen Sutermeister of the Norwich Survey. However, my perceptions
of borough history were most deeply influenced by my M.Phil.
supervisor, Professor Geoffrey Martin. Needless to say, the errors
that I do not doubt exist in this study - which is but a way-station
on the journey towards a better understanding of borough
government - are due entirely to my own failings. A debt of
thanks is also owed to the staffs of local and national archives
who dealt with my many and sometimes unreasonable demands with
much patience and kindness. In particular I think of Mr. David
Lee of the Public Record Office and Ms. Susan Maddock, King's
Lynn archivist at the Norfolk Record Office, who managed to
produce documents for my perusal under the most trying circumstances.
Finally, I must acknowledge the kindness of His Grace The Duke
of Norfolk, E.M., C.B., C.B.E., M.C., in allowing access to his
archives at Arundel Castle.

INTRODUCTION
Structure of Borough Government |
Social and Economic Background of Office-Holders
Monopolisation of Office |
Attitudes Towards Office-holding |
Professionalism in Administration
Quality of Government |
Conflict and Solidarity in Urban Politics
CONCLUSION